The development of intellectual property rights has long been celebrated for creating incentives for innovation and progress. In the global tech landscape, patents are often viewed as crucial for fostering innovation, safeguarding inventors from having their creations copied without compensation. This system has become so ingrained that it is difficult for Western audiences to envision a world where innovation thrives without the “protection” of intellectual property rights.

Huaqiangbei Electronics Market

The rapid development of Shenzhen, often referred to as China’s Silicon Valley, can be attributed to its Shanzhai market, a space where patent laws hold no sway. Shanzhai, often reduced to China’s “copycat culture,” is a derogatory Cantonese term for “knockoffs” or “pirated goods.” It literally translates to “mountain camp”–meant to mimic people in rural areas who, unable to afford luxury goods or officially produced DVDs, resort to buying poorly made pirated items. The word used to be an inscription and evidence to the Western world that China can only copy, not innovate. However, as scholars come to deconstruct China’s Shanzhai market, some find that it holds the power to decolonize technology

Western patent systems are often lauded for promoting technological progress, but they come at a high cost. Innovation becomes an exclusive club where only those with the resources to navigate the complex and expensive patent process can truly participate. For a long time, knowledge of the tech industry has been concentrated in the hands of a small group of elites. This has been particularly problematic in the Global South, where “technology transfer” programs have largely failed to empower local communities. Instead of building self-reliant ecosystems, these programs often leave nations dependent on expensive, proprietary technology. The reason for the failed attempt is simply lack of resources and human capital in the third world needed to create their own products from the opaque technology. Western patent systems have operated as gatekeepers, controlling who can access innovation and who remains excluded. The same system that protects the right of the creator also decides who has the right to create. Shanzhai, in turn, provides a new form of innovation–it endorses the right not only to use a device but to alter and reclaim the ownership of it. At Shenzhen, technical devices are rapidly modified and produced to meet diverse needs. It also caters to marginalized communities, offering features like dual SIM cards (a decade before iPhone provided the feature) or counterfeit detection tools. The designers of Shanzhai devices build on each other’s work, compete and collaborate in a decentralized market. They essentially create an open-source knowledge commons where people learn, create, and contribute in a fast-paced, cooperative environment. Wang describes the phenomenon as “an unapologetic confrontation with Western ideas of intellectual property”. It shows that pirated goods do have the potential of facilitating knowledge sharing and innovation at an extremely low cost. The open-source-like production ecosystem allows innovation to flourish without the strict enforcement of traditional intellectual property regimes. 

But does Shanzhai inherently carry a liberating and decolonizing force? Not necessarily. Shenzhen’s tech ecosystem, powerful as it is, heavily relies on free trade and gray-market labor. Shenzhen’s rising labor costs and the worsened trade environment between the U.S. and China have led factories to branch out in sub-Saharan Africa and Southeast Asia. Exporting Shenzhen-style production also brings with it Shenzhen’s labor practices, and several Chinese companies have been criticized for poor wages and working conditions in their overseas operations. The economic benefits of these ventures often flow back to China, with the host countries seeing fewer gains–a phenomenon we’ve already witnessed in instances of Western-centric technology transfers. As a result, while Shenzhai challenges traditional technological power structures by operating an open-source ecosystem, it does not address the broader issues of labor exploitation and uneven economic development.

In recent years, China has also begun to formalize its relationship with intellectual property due to external pressures, particularly in response to China’s commitments to the World Trade Organization (WTO). As part of its global integration, China has had to adopt stricter IP laws to align with international standards. The local government in Shenzhen, for instance, now provides grants for filing patents and establishing maker spaces to encourage formal innovation. As the city moves beyond the production of low-cost gadgets and focuses on more sophisticated products—such as artificial intelligence devices and app-controlled technologies—the need for stronger IP regimes has become increasingly apparent. 

Once a symbol of grassroots innovation and a challenge to Western patent systems, Shanzhai has gradually been overshadowed by more sophisticated, branded products as China’s tech industry aligns itself with international IP standards. However, this fading influence does not imply that open-source information sharing is merely a historical stage in the evolution of a successful IP regime. On the contrary, Shanzhai has demonstrated that open-source models can serve as a powerful alternative to proprietary systems, offering a decentralized and accessible approach to innovation. 

As the global tech landscape evolves, the principles that drove Shanzhai—collaboration, adaptation, and shared knowledge—remain relevant. They challenge the notion that patents and exclusivity are the only pathways to progress. The future of innovation may well depend on whether these open-source practices can adapt and thrive alongside, or even in opposition to, formal intellectual property systems. In this sense, Shanzhai may have been the starting point, but the idea of open-source ecosystems remains a viable and potentially transformative alternative to traditional IP regimes.